Pages

Monday, 17 February 2014

Currency Market Intervention

In every big-bank currency trading room in major financial centers, there is a direct line to the open market trading desk of the central bank. When that line lights up, the whole dealing room erupts. That line is reserved for open market intervention by the central bank, and when it rings, it usually means only one thing: The central bank is intervening in the market.

Intervention refers to central banks buying or selling currencies in the open market to drive currency rates in a desired direction. Direct intervention in the market is usually taken only as a last resort. It also may be a stopgap measure to stabilize markets upset by extreme events, such as a terrorist attack or rumors of a financial institution’s failure. When it’s not necessitated by emergency circumstances, markets are generally aware of the increasing risks of intervention. 

Open market intervention is usually preceded by several less-blunt forms of official intervention. The idea from the governments’ point of view is to get as much bang for the buck as possible before committing real money. Remember, Central banks have limited firepower in relation to the overall market, so they have to pick their spots well. Sometimes, the government's objective is simply to slow a market move to restore financial market stability, and less drastic forms of intervention are not yet necessary. Some of the more subtle forms of intervention are

  • Verbal intervention or jawboning: These are efforts by finance ministry or central bank officials to publicly suggest that current market directions are undesirable. Basically, it amounts to trying to talk up or talk down a particular currency’s value. For example, if the Japanese MOF is intent on preventing further JPY strength to protect its export sector, but the USD/JPY rate keeps moving lower, senior MOF officials may indicate that “excessive exchange rate movements are undesirable.” This message signals currency traders to reduce their USD selling/JPY buying or risk the potential consequences. If the market ignores the warning, the MOF may take it up a notch and indicate that it is “closely monitoring exchange rates,” which is language typically used before actual open market intervention.

  • Checking rates: This is the central bank’s open market desk ringing in on the direct line to major currency banks’ trading desks. The traders don’t know if it’s going to be a real intervention or not, but they still react instinctively based on previously indicated preferences. Even rumors of a central bank checking rates are enough to trigger a significant market reaction.
In terms of actual open market intervention, there are several different forms it can take, all depending on which and how many central banks are participating. The more the merrier; better still, there’s strength in numbers.

  • Unilateral intervention: This is intervention by a single central bank to buy or sell its own currency. Unilateral intervention is generally the least effective form of intervention, because the government perceived (usually correctly) to be acting alone and without the support of other major governments. Markets will typically revert to the earlier direction after the intervention has run its course to test the central bank’s resolve and to see if it’s intent on stopping the move or simply slowing it. The   MOF/BOJ intervention in 2003 and 2004 was unilateral intervention.

  • Joint intervention: This is when two central banks intervene together to shift the direction of their shared currency pair. For example, if the ECB and the SNB are concerned about Swiss-franc weakness versus the euro, they may decide to intervene jointly to sell EUR/CHF. This is a clear sign to markets that the two governments are prepared to work together to alter the direction of that pair’s exchange rate.

  • Concerted intervention: This is when multiple central banks join together to intervene in the market simultaneously. This is the most powerful and effective type of intervention, because it suggests unity of purpose by multiple governments. Concerted intervention is not done lightly by major central banks and markets don’t take it lightly either. It’s the equivalent of a sledgehammer to the head. Concerted intervention frequently results in major long-term trend changes.

In term of the impact of intervention, different governments are given different degrees of respect by the market. Due to the frequency of past interventions and constant threats of it, the Japanese tend to get the least respect. The BOE, the SNB, and the ECB are treated with considerably more respect by markets, with the ECB being the linchpin of credibility for the Eurozone. Finally, when the U.S. Treasury (via the Fed) intervenes, it’s considered a major event, and the market usually respects the intervention.

There is a difference between a central bank intervening for its own "account and a central bank intervening on behalf of another foreign central bank. For example, during the MOF/BOJ intervention campaign in 2003 and 2004, there were several instances where the U.S. Fed bought USD/JPY during the New York trading day. The first reaction was that the U.S. Treasury was joining in and supporting the intervention by the MOF/BOJ, and this amplified the effect of the intervention. But the U.S. Treasury later denied that it had ordered the intervention. What happened was that the BOJ asked the New York Fed to intervene on its behalf during the New York trading session. Central banks have standing agreements to act as each others’ representatives in their local markets. So even though the New York Fed bought dollars, it bought them for the B0J.

Does intervention work? That is a question that frequently comes up when central banks get involved. The simple answer is an unequivocal “Yes, but ….” Intervention is most effective when it’s backed by monetary policy moving in the same direction, such as expected higher interest rates to support a weak currency or easier monetary policy to weaken a strong one. Even then, interest rate changes are no guarantee that the intervention will be successful.

In the short run, the intervention may seem fruitless and counterproductive. This is especially-the case with unilateral intervention. The market typically rejects the unilateral intervention and reverts to pushing the market in the direction opposed by the intervention. This situation can go on for weeks and months or in the MOF/BOJ’s case in 2003 to 2004, years. When it’s a joint or concerted intervention, the results are usually more immediate and successful. 
 

Blogger news

Blogroll

View My Stats